|
By Hong Jiang, assistant professor at
University of Wisconsin
Introduction
Since the 1980s, widespread transitions
have occurred in socialist countries such as China. Marxist
ideologies have been weakened, active engagements with the
market have occurred, and decentralization of governance has
taken place (Lavigne 1999; McMillan
and Naughton 1996; Turner 1999). While post-socialist
transitions have a distinct historical and social background,
many of the changes are global in nature. Decentralization is
one example. In developed countries, decentralization has
expanded in the provision of public services (Bennett 1990), and
the community-based environmental movement has been championed
as a grand vision (Weber 2000). In developing countries,
especially in Africa and Latin America, decentralization has
been promoted by the World Bank and other international
organizations as a prerequisite for sustainable use and
conservation (World Bank 1997). The perceived success of
decentralization in post-socialist countries has encouraged the
view that decentralization is part of good governance, and that
it should be extended to conservation and resource management.
China’s decentralization is unique in
several aspects. First, instead of community-level management,
which has been a common form of decentralization globally, China
has drastically devolved decision-making powers to resource
users (Unger 2002). Since the 1980s, most agricultural and much
pasture land has been distributed to households. Second, various
levels of the government have played crucial roles in the
decentralization process. Decentralization was an important part
of the national policy shift from revolutionary politics to
economic growth, and regional and local governments continue to
influence land use in important ways. This stands in sharp
contrast to much of Africa and Latin America, where state
involvement is weak and it is mainly international agencies,
donors, and NGOs that have provided the engine for decentralized
resource use (Shroeder 1999; Sundberg 1999). Third, China’s
decentralization has come with an economic reform policy that
aimed to reverse the economic failure of the former collective
management (Jia and Lin 1994; Lin 1999). This increasing drive
for development and growing reliance on the market have resulted
in environmental issues being viewed through economic lenses (Jiang
1999). The unique Chinese experience provides an important
socio-political context in which to explore decentralized
pastureland use in this paper.
The complicated results of
decentralization have been widely acknowledged (Luts and
Caldecott 1996; Ribot 1999). While some champion
decentralization’s positive effects on environmental
sustainability (e.g., Bakir 2001; de Oliveria 2002), many
studies reveal the unfulfilled promises of decentralization.
Sundberg and Gray (this volume) suggest that community-level
resource use can often exacerbate existing inequalities within
the community, and as such, there is no guarantee for equitable
use; Lane (2003) warns of the manipulation of decentralized
resource management by local power holders; Nemarundwe (2004)
argues that overlapping authority at the community level can
serve to frustrate, rather than clarify, resource use; and
Williams and Wells (1996) and Zhang (2000) report cases of
reduced funding and concern for conservation as the power is
decentralized and responsibility for environmental initiatives
is placed on regional and local governments. While political,
administrative, and financial difficulties can impact
decentralized resource use, ecological dynamics add another
level of complexity (Leach, Mearns, and Scoones 1999). As
Assetto et al. (2003) indicate, decentralization is a necessary
but not a sufficient condition for environmental protection and
equitable resource use.
This paper joins in the study of
decentralized resource use by analyzing the impact of
household-based pastureland management in Uxin Ju, a community
in western Inner Mongolia, China. After pastureland is
distributed and fenced, sandy land reclamation becomes a growing
concern as degradation rises. While household-based pastureland
use and reclamation have brought about economic growth to the
area, I argue that their effects are not uniformly positive when
cultural change and ecological processes are taken into
consideration. Instead of environmental conservation within
designated protected areas, I discuss pastureland use that is an
integral part of rural livelihood. Issues to be explored here
are relevant to the second wave of conservation that emphasizes
conservation with sustainable use (Brandon, Redford, and
Sanderson 1998). While much of this paper will discuss more
aggressive approaches to resource use that prioritize economy
over ecology, toward the end I will discuss a renewed need for
stricter conservation precisely because of this aggressive use.
This chapter proceeds as follows. In the
first section, I will introduce how decentralization is
implemented in Inner Mongolia, and its forms on the landscape in
Uxin Ju, particularly the building of fences. Section two
examines ways in which sandy land is reclaimed inside fences.
The third section examines the impact of fencing on the
Mongolian lifestyle, asserting the far-reaching cultural
implications of resource privatization. While in general, fences
have led the Mongols away from traditional nomadism, ecological
processes of pastureland management have resulted in uneven
landscape changes and concomitant inequality among the Mongols.
The next two sections explore such landscape and socio-economic
differentiation, and discuss the need for a less-aggressive
approach to pastureland conservation. This paper concludes with
a critique of household-level resource management from the
perspectives of ecological processes, cultural change, and
management scales.
Household-based pastureland management
Uxin Ju is a Mongolian township situated
in Uxin banner, Ih Ju league in Inner Mongolia Autonomous
Region, China. It has four administrative villages (or gacha
in Mongolian): Uxin Ju, Bayintaolegai, Chahanmiao, and Buridu
(see Figure 1). Its population is dominated by Mongols, and its
economy is based on sheep and cattle husbandry. Much of its
1,744 km2 (or 2.6 million mu) is dominated by
sandy land (83 percent), and land forms include upland (usually
sandy), lowland, and sand dunes in between. The sandy upland and
dune areas, if vegetated, are covered by Artemisia ordosica
and Caragana spp. In between the moving sand dunes are
small depressions where water conditions are favorable, and
willow shrubs (Salix psammophila) can take root. The
lowland, which has the most favorable water conditions, is
dominated by grassy species Carex duriuscula and
Achnatherum splendens and provides the best quality
pastures in Uxin Ju.
China’s economic reform has brought about
profound change to the landscape of Uxin Ju. Faced with the
failure of the collective economy, the Chinese central
government launched an economic reform policy in the late 1970s
after the death of Mao. The reform started in the farming areas,
where, under a Household Responsibility System (HRS), cropland
and other production materials, previously managed by the
communes, were distributed to the households. The HRS was soon
spread to the pastoral areas, and the Inner Mongolia regional
government took the lead in devising and implementing a two-tier
HRS: both livestock and pastureland would be distributed to
households. While the livestock was sold to households as
private property, the state retained ownership of land, the
use-rights to which were contracted to the households. The
distribution of pastureland has been subject to periodic
adjustment based on household democratic change. In Uxin Ju and
many areas of Inner Mongolia, pastureland distribution was twice
adjusted, in 1991 and 1997; the last adjustment also extended
the contract terms to 30 to 50 years from an unspecified period
(Jiang n.d.).
The household contract has the de facto
effect of privatization, albeit a limited one, since land cannot
be bought or sold but only have its use-rights transferred.
Williams (2001) traces the shift to household-based management
to the global distrust of common resource institutions and the
common belief that privatization will promote ecological
protection. Decentralization was widely acclaimed by the Chinese
government as a cure for the economic and environmental problems
of the collective management in the Mao era. The local area
newspaper in Uxin Ju, The Ordos Daily (Feb. 2, 1989),
celebrated the pastureland distribution with an article entitled
“Now the Pasture Has Masters,” which asserted that this
decentralization is the best way to care for the land and to
develop the economy. Consequences of privatization will be
discussed in greater detail later, but, in brief, the acclaimed
promise of household-based pastureland use has been undermined
by ecological, cultural, and economic problems.
Not all of China’s pastoral areas have
implemented the two-tier HRS. Some have kept the pastureland as
a common resource (Banks 2001), or demarcated household pastures
only on paper (Thwaites et al. 1998), or fenced the pastureland
only partially (Williams 2001). But in Uxin Ju, pastureland was
fenced soon after its distribution to households in 1984-1985.
Such a wide variation in pastureland decentralization is
attributed to differing priorities of regional and local
governments, which are responsible for the actual implementation
of many of the reform policies (Jiang n.d.). In Inner Mongolia,
while the regional government issued policies regarding HRS,
methods of implementation became more detailed at the lower
levels of government. The actual pastureland distribution was
carried out by village (gacha) committees, which
stipulated distribution rules. In the communities that I have
investigated around Uxin Ju, two types of distribution rules
were employed: one, based on strict equality of all people, was
to distribute pastureland according to the number of persons in
a household; the second was to take into consideration both the
number of persons and livestock in a household. Uxin Ju followed
the first rule. To minimize travel distance, distribution plans
attempted to assign pastureland to the nearest households
(instead of giving each household a piece of each type of land
as in farming areas; see Kung and Liu 1997). To account for
variations in species, coverage, and productivity, all
pastureland was assessed according to usable biomass and
converted to “standard pasture,” each mu corresponding to
100 kg of dry forage. The built-in structural equality in
pastureland distribution comes from the Mao era’s ethos (Kung
and Liu 1997); such equality, although subject to cadre
manipulations, helps minimize the struggle for access that is
common in the decentralized resource use in Africa (Gray, this
volume) and Latin America (Sundberg, this volume). In Uxin Ju,
however, initial conditions of equality have been undermined by
socio-economic stratifications resulting from uneven landscape
change, as will be discussed later.
Barbed wire fences quickly followed
pasture distribution, creating enclosures called kulum by
the Mongols. From the experience of eastern Inner Mongolia (Thwaites
et al. 1998), it is clear that unless boundaries are demarcated
with fences, pastureland distribution cannot be adhered to,
since livestock will roam into unfenced pastures. In Uxin Ju,
the people’s ready acceptance of the concept of fences came from
the early socialist period when they built large enclosures in
order to protect planted trees and crops, as well as to conserve
pasture for the cutting of hay. In the 1980s, after the
pastureland distribution, the practical need for fences quickly
became clear since households had to protect their allotted
pastures from turning into commons. The government encouraged
fencing by providing subsidies. Data from Ih Ju League show that
from 1978 to 1996, government funds accounted for 23.3 percent
of total investment in pasture enclosure (Liu and Wang 1998).
The rest of the funds came from individual households. In a 1998
interview, Bayingsonbuer, a Mongol living in Bayintaolegai
gacha, said that since 1985, his household had spent over
20,000 Yuan (approximately US $2,400) on fences. This is a hefty
sum given that the 1998 per capita income was only 1,952 Yuan
(US $235). By the late 1990s, all contracted pasturelands in
Uxin Ju, including those assigned to the poor, had been fenced.
Sandy land reclamation
With fences came more aggressive use of
the pastureland as well as increased emphasis on sandy land
improvement. Since the implementation of economic reform, China
has paid more attention to rural environmental issues, and has
attempted to use ecological science to guide environmental
management. The term “ecological construction” came into wide
use in the 1990s, advocating the repair of land degradation
using ecological principles (Jiang n.d.). In reality, however,
the implementation of ecological programs by all levels of the
government has focused on aggressive approaches that undermine
ecological processes. In Uxin Ju, for example, instead of
protecting or recovering the original species, improvement
efforts only considered biomass. Trees, which were nonexistent
on the natural landscape, have been planted, along with exotic
shrub and grass species. Even the expansion of irrigated
cropland has been seen as sign of ecological improvement.
Concern for sustainability has been tilted toward the economy,
while ecology has largely been seen as providing a necessary
service.
Sandy land reclamation entails the
conversion of degraded sandy pastureland and moving sand into
usable pastures, and it is achieved through two kinds of
efforts: transplanting and seeding, both followed by a
prohibition of grazing in enclosures, at least in the summer,
and sometimes year-round, for three years. The timing and length
of these grazing bans have been determined and monitored by the
local government, and violators are fined. Transplanting uses
seedlings of trees and shrubs, and is practiced in enclosures
closer to houses. In recent years, the total transplanted area
per year has reached 30,000 mu or more. The most commonly
transplanted tree species is the willow (Salix matsudana),
and shrubs include local species such as Salix psammophila,
Artemisia ordosica, and Caragana spp., and non-local
species such as Hedysarum mongolicum and H. scoparium.
Methods of sand dune reclamation, which have been developed
locally since the 1960s, are described as “blocking the front
and hauling the back; boots first, then gowns and lastly hats.”
That is, trees and shrubs are planted first on the lower part of
leeward (front) and windward (back) sides. As the vegetation
develops at the bottom of the sand dune like “boots,” the
movement of sand is constrained, and the sand dunes are lowered.
Planting slowly moves up to the sand dunes and dresses them in
green “gowns” and finally covers them with “hats.” This method
has worked well in some locations and has converted sandy land
into usable pastures. It meets great difficulty, however, at the
landscape scale, as will be discussed later.
Seeding is done with the help of airplanes
that are operated by the local government. In 2001, Uxin Ju
seeded 122,000 mu of sandy land. Airplane sowing is a
labor-saving method of land improvement used mostly in large
continuous areas of sandy, semi-vegetated, and low-lying land.
In addition to shrubs, grasses such as Melilotus albus
and Medicago sativa are also seeded. Since the area to be
sown has to be large enough to justify the operation cost,
airplane seeding goes beyond the boundaries of fences and
requires coordination among multiple households. Since
decentralization, this is one of the ways in which collective
management maintains great importance. Funds for seeding are
allocated from the government to the village. Once an area is
chosen for operation by the technical staff in Uxin Ju, the
households involved are expected to participate. If no rain
follows seeding in ten to fifteen days, the operation will most
likely fail. In most cases, even if seeds germinate, success is
only partial because subsequent droughts may cause the young
seedlings to die. The government reports that the average
success rate for airplane seeding is 80 percent, but my
interviews suggest that the actual seedling survival rate
averages 50 percent or lower. In the recent drought from 1999 to
2001, most seeds failed to germinate. Regardless of seeding
success, the participating households are obligated to follow
the grazing ban for a three-year period after seeding. From the
fourth year on, they can graze only in the cold season. Most
households prefer to have their pasture seeded because of
potential near-future gain, so there have not been major
conflicts between the participating households and the
government. However, there are cases when households are poor
and have difficulty paying their share of the seeding cost.
After their pasture is seeded and closed, most of these
households have to rent pastureland from other households at
0.25 Yuan per sheep per day; this only increases the financial
burden on poor households.
Reclamation is a joint venture between the
government and individual households. Although land-use
decisions are made by the households, the government still plays
a crucial role in guiding land use through managerial and
financial means. All government leaders are allocated
responsibility to help a certain number of households in the
reclamation process. Each year, Uxin Ju has spring and fall
planting sprees during which all leaders go to their selected
households to participate in planting. Each gacha also
designates several large areas for concentrated efforts, and
households that contracted the pasture of these areas are
expected to plant trees there during the planting seasons.
Government funding for planting and seeding is available through
specific programs such as the North China Revegetation and
Return Cultivation to Trees programs from the national
government and the Family Pasture program from the regional
government. Specific programs change over time, but overall,
most of the seedlings and seeds are purchased with government
funds, and labor input comes from households. In airplane
seeding, the banner government paid 100 percent of the
operational cost and seeds before 1995; now, it pays only
slightly more than half, while requiring that households pay 2.5
Yuan per mu.
Most households actively participate in
sandy land reclamation in order to augment household pastures. A
sample of the household surveys that I conducted in 2001 shows
that 48 percent of the sandy land had been transplanted or
seeded by the households, although not all efforts were
successful. In addition, the number of trees (willow and poplar)
has increased drastically. Official statistics [author: what
year?] show that the number of trees totaled 80,000, with each
household averaging ninety trees. By 2001, my sampled households
each owned, on average, 2,800 trees. These trees, along with
irrigated cropland and some planted shrubs, are located in what
is called “cultivation enclosures.” Although not used for
grazing, this type of enclosure is the most productive and also
the newest modification to the landscape that makes the pastoral
area most farm-like.
Other than the regularly contracted
pastureland, there are also “wastelands” that were not initially
distributed in 1984. These are moving sand areas or sand dunes,
called “sandy waste.” Instead of allowing these lands to lay
“waste,” the local government contracted them out to households
on a voluntary basis and encouraged households to reclaim them.
According to the local policy, any wasteland reclaimed will be
awarded to the households that improved upon it as additional
tax-free pasture in addition to their original allocation. Since
all usable pastureland had been distributed, the only way to
increase pastureland was to reclaim these wastelands. By 1991,
most wastelands had been contracted. In most cases, large areas
of sandy wasteland were contracted by multiple households. Some
wastelands in remote locations were rented to outside groups
(such as the First Chemical Engineering Plant of Ih Ju league).
My interviews suggest that some households have already improved
upon these wastelands with fences and planting; others have
started to make plans for reclamation.
Changing Pastoral Life Under Fences
Land use concerns are not only economic
but also cultural. As Turner (2002) points out, ways of making a
living are closely related to ethnic identity. The majority (90
percent) of those managing Uxin Ju’s rural landscape are
Mongols, whose traditional lifestyle was nomadic grazing. As
pastures and sand dunes become constrained by fences, mobility
for both livestock and pastoralists ends. In livestock raising,
increases in cropping and planting have shifted the past
reliance on natural pasture to increasing dependence on
human-produced biomass. On the positive side, planted trees
(leaves), shrubs, grasses, as well as crops have provided
additional forage and feed, and this has made livestock grazing
more resistant to drought and winter shortage. The pastoral
economy has thus been improved. But economic benefits come with
costs and consequences. First, as a result of pasture
improvement and protection, goats, a traditional livestock, have
been eliminated since they “destroy the planted trees” and
“browse bare the pastures” (Wushen Qi 2001). Goats’ durability
and adaptability to the dry, shrubby vegetation has now become
their liability. After several decades of reduction, by 1999,
the number of goats had been reduced to 73 from 40,000-60,000 in
the 1970s. Goats may indeed be maladapted to the newly created
landscape, yet the impact of their removal on local diet and
health warrants careful research. A second consequence is that
rotational grazing, practiced over large areas in the past, has
now become impossible. While livestock privatization encourages
the growth of sheep numbers, sheep are now grazed for longer
periods of time (two months at a minimum) on one piece of
pasture within fences.
Rotational grazing in enclosures is the
Mongols’ way of adapting to the new social and environmental
situations. Traditional nomadic grazing involves frequent
movement of herds on large open pastureland. Uxin Ju people call
it zouchang (walking the field). This extensive mobility
not only protects the pastureland from overuse, but also
encourages more efficient use of pastureland resources (Humphrey
and Sneath 1999). Nomadic grazing started to be limited after
the 1600s when the Qing court restricted Mongol princes to fixed
banner lands (Barfield 1989). With the establishment of communes
in 1958 under the socialist regime, land was further divided
according to the basic production unit of a brigade (about 20 to
30 households). Limited long-distance movement was still
possible as Uxin Ju swapped land use with Otog banner to the
west and grazed on their highland stony shrub in the summer.
Now, with fences and household management, pastureland is too
divided to allow for any extensive movement of livestock.
Pastoralists have adjusted to this new pastoral condition by
rotational grazing on their small patches of pasture inside
fences. Grazing on other households’ pastureland is still
practiced, but the relationship is that of land rent rather than
land-use swapping. Some households rent pastureland from others
at a fixed fee and use it more intensively; some pay according
to sheep number and length of grazing to graze their sheep on
others’ allocated pastureland. However, neither of these methods
helps protect the pastureland as mobility did in the past. It is
not surprising that Williams (2001) suspects that pastureland
distribution might have marked a greater transformation of
pastoral life than collectivization in 1958.
With fences, the migratory routine of
human life is disappearing, and in its place is the settled
routine of a busy life. Although livestock can be left to graze
in fenced enclosures without much supervision, thus reducing
labor requirements for grazing, overall labor demands have
drastically increased. With trees to plant, tree leaves to cut,
crops to irrigate and cultivate, fences to mend, and more work
required to feed the improved sheep variety and to prevent
disease, pastoralists’ daily routines have become much more
labor-intensive. To illustrate, Bayinsongbuer complained that he
had to spend two to three months each year mending fences. The
cropping season is especially labor-intensive for pastoralists
who are not used to the rhythm of farming. It is no wonder that
my interviewees commented about the loss of leisure life. When
asked whether they would trade their current busier but
materially richer lifestyle for their past leisure, however,
most of my interviewees indicated that they would not. This
juxtaposition of complaint and acceptance points to the
pastoralists’ internal conflicts between tradition and change.
Williams (2001) maintains that pastureland
privatization represents Chinese cultural and political
imposition. Household use is a familiar relationship to the land
for the Chinese farmers, and the tendency to fix people to
particular locations comes from the farming tradition. But for
the Mongols, pastureland has traditionally been used as a common
resource. As a traditionally Mongolian area, Uxin Ju has long
been under the influence of Chinese culture and politics, and
change in land use is closely related to the process of
Sinicization. I would submit that in Uxin Ju, such influence is
not as hegemonic as Williams suggests. Many Mongols have learned
to adapt to the lifestyle change under fences, and have started
to embrace planting and cropping as an integral part of
Mongolian identity (see Jiang 2004 for details). Ironically, the
Mongols’ acceptance of sedentarized agropastoralism, while
culturally empowering, seems only to accelerate the loss of
traditional nomadism.
Ecological processes and uneven
landscape consequences of reclamation
Unlike flat land, sandy land is undulating
and rolling; it is a landscape of elasticity created by the
movement of sand and pasture. As sand dunes move with the
direction of the wind, new pastures are created on locations the
dunes have just vacated. This dune land remains resilient to
moving sand, in contrast to the common view that this land is
fragile and easily sandified (e.g. Sun Jinzhu 1990). Bare sand
dunes serve important roles in supporting functions of the
landscape. Precipitation quickly filtrates into the ground to
supplement the groundwater, which in turn, supplies water for
the lowland. Moving sand dunes are considered areas of “water
provision.” Instead of being “wastelands,” moving dunes are a
crucial component on the landscape that nurtures the key lowland
pastures. Research done by the Chinese Academy of Science led by
Zhang Xinshi shows that if planting on sand dunes is too dense,
not only will the established vegetation die off after a few
years, but the adjacent lowland will also be adversely affected
(Zhang 2001).
Two reasons explain why moving sand is now
considered a problem to society. First, pastureland overuse has
caused more sand to be exposed. Not only has the number of
livestock increased but grazing intensity has also been
heightened with fences. In 1998, official statistics showed that
about 50 percent of Uxin Ju was occupied by moving sand, much of
which was considered to be caused by human misuse. Many scholars
emphasize the human causes and human control of sand expansion
(Huang et al. 1986; Sun 1990), and most people I interviewed
believe that much of the sandy land can be improved. Expansion
of sand is seen as a major problem that reduces usable
pastureland. Instead of seeing moving sand as a natural function
of the landscape, scholars and local people use it as a measure
of degradation. Once put in the category of degraded land, sandy
land has to be reformed. Second, the mobility of sand
challenges sedentary lifestyles. In nomadic societies, as sand
moved, so did people, thus, the human relationship with the
sandy land environment was more harmonious (Chen 2001). Such
mobility, however, was only possible when intensity of use was
low. Now that people are more densely settled, mobility of sand
has become hazardous to houses, animal shelters, and roads
(Huang et al. 1986). The elasticity of the dune landscape
contradicts with the fixed allocation of household pastureland.
As a result, households attempt to constrain sand dunes and to
prevent dune sand from moving onto their pastureland.
Despite the human efforts to secure the
landscape with fences, natural processes continue: sand moves
across fences. When sand control is not successful, movement of
sand across fences creates conflicts between households such as
was the case for Ererdun and his neighbor. Ererdun has made
tremendous efforts to reclaim most of his sandy land, but his
neighbor in the windward northwest direction has not controlled
his sand in the enclosure adjacent to Ererdun’s. A moving sand
dune, previously 20 m away, has now crossed the fence and
covered Ererdun’s pasture, consequently creating a new piece of
pastureland within the neighbor’s fence. With pastureland
distribution fixed for 30 years, such neighborly disputes cannot
be truly mitigated. Like wildlife that cannot be restrained
within conservation boundaries (Naughton-Treves et al. 2003),
moving sand does not obey the authority of fences.
Sandy land reclamation inside fences has
come with an unintended environmental cost across the landscape.
The rapid increase in trees and irrigation has lowered
groundwater levels, a problem which has only been exacerbated by
the recent drought from 1999 to 2001. This has caused the
reduction in inter-dune vegetation and enabled the expansion of
sand dunes. Although tremendous effort is devoted to keeping the
sandy land “fixed,” it can only succeed in limited areas, and
given the connection of the landscape to groundwater, this
fixation of landscape in some locations has come at the cost of
more moving sand in other locations. With groundwater remaining
a “common” resource, household-based pastureland use produces
ecological externalities that have not been considered in the
privatization of land use. As a result, despite—and partly
because of—an upswing in land reclamation, bare sandy areas have
also increased. A new pattern on the landscape, a landscape of
polarization, has been created, with the expansion and spatial
congregation of both planted trees and moving sand dunes. Remote
sensing analysis shows that from 1973 to 1997, vegetation with
high biomass (mostly planted) in Uxin Ju increased from 102,000
to 428,700 mu, and moving sand also increased from
645,000 to over 1.2 million mu (Jiang 2004). The bounded
condition produced by fencing, while increasing the incentives
for investment and reclamation, is leading to environmental
problems on a broader scale.
While the increases in planted trees and
moving sand may somehow counterbalance each other in terms of
the total production of the sandy land, lowland pasture remains
victimized by sandy land reclamation. The lowering of
groundwater directly worsens the lowland water conditions.
Groundwater reduction has been confirmed by remote sensing
analysis and interviews. Remote sensing analysis shows that from
1973 to 1997, the area of surface water decreased from 79,890 to
36,500 mu. Since lowland surface water is linked with the
shallow layer of groundwater, a reduction in surface water
bodies serves to indicate a lowered groundwater table.
Interviewees pointed out a 2 to 4 m lowering of the groundwater
table in their irrigation wells. The increased number of
livestock and lack of grazing mobility have only worsened the
deterioration of lowland pasture. One interviewee commented that
“in the past sheep could hide in Carex pasture, but now
you can see rabbits running in it.” The degradation of Uxin Ju’s
jewel lowland pasture reduces the capacity for livestock
grazing, and has, in part, resulted in the need for sandy land
reclamation. An informant from Buridu gacha, Baole, put
it aptly, “In the past livestock could eat their fill on the
pasture, but now, they have to rely on planted fodder and feed
as supplement.” The forage and feed provided by tree leaves and
planted shrubs, grass, and crops, however, have come at a
greater cost in terms of human labor. A cycle of increased use,
reclamation, and degradation has been set off by
decentralization.
Newly created inequality, and a new
need for conservation
The sandy land environment, highly
variable in time and space and highly influenced by human
interventions, is better described by disequilibrium dynamics (Behnke,
Scoones and Kerven 1994; Wu and Loucks 1995). This
requires that we understand environmental dynamics beyond the
aggregate notion of degradation or improvement (Leach, Mearns,
and Scoones, 1999). Ecological processes connect neighbors and
communities, and uneven changes on the landscape call for the
sharing of ecological and economic risks. But privatization has
effectively destroyed the culture and economy of sharing, and
the fixing of pastureland to individual households and fences
has created winners and losers.
Inequality among households has emerged.
Three kinds of households are poor: those with disabilities,
those lacking labor, and those having poor-quality pastureland.
It is probably common in any society that the first two kinds of
households suffer from poverty; the last kind of poverty has to
do with fences. As mentioned earlier, pastureland is distributed
according to where people live. People with lowland and less
sandy pastures have not only better grazing conditions but also
more favorable land to improve upon. People living on sandy land
have sandy pastures, and fences prohibit them from grazing
elsewhere. Although pasture areas allocated to households are
equalized through their conversion to standard pasture, much of
the sandy pasture has become even sandier due to the overall
pattern of landscape change, as explained earlier. Households
living on more sandy areas disproportionately bear more of the
negative ecological consequences. A clear illustration of such
conditions is provided by Labai and her two adult sons, one of
the poor households the government supported in recent years.
They have 2,400 mu of poor-quality sandy pastureland,
equivalent to 134 mu in standard pasture. With limits on
sheep grazing, they did not have sufficient cash to invest in
irrigation wells and equipment, so they lagged behind other
households in diversifying land use. Their lack of capital in
reclamation only exacerbated the degradation of their allocated
pastureland. In 1997, they took a government loan to dig an
irrigation well for ten mu of cropland, and the
government supported them with cash for seeds and fertilizers.
They had only 750 trees, compared to the average of 2,800 trees
from my sample households. Although they did have enough food,
their poverty clearly showed in their almost bare house when I
visited in 1999.
The spatial association of sandy pasture
and poverty is also found over large areas. Buridu gacha,
for example, is more sandy, and reclamation efforts there have
not achieved anticipated results. Planting did draw sand dunes
lower than before, but the total area of sandy land has
increased. An analysis of remote sensing images shows that from
1973 to 1997, moving sand in Buridu more than doubled in area,
increasing from 316,000 mu to 645,000 mu. In
comparison, during the same period, Chahanmiao gacha had
only a 37 percent increase of moving sand from 123,000 mu
to 168,000 mu. Given the rapid expansion of moving sand,
people in Buridu are much less sanguine about human efforts to
improve sandy land than those in Chahanmiao gacha.
In 2001, in an attempt to recover
seriously degraded pastureland and to help the poor households
living on it, the Inner Mongolian regional government launched
an “ecological migration” program that funds the relocation of
people from the most degraded areas. The program was initiated
as a response to a new central agenda to develop the western
regions. In 1999, to promote economic development in China’s
west, which had lagged behind the eastern region, the
beneficiary of economic reform policies, the Chinese government
put forth various policies and financial incentives under the
umbrella of a Western Region Development (WRD) strategy. Since
much of the “western region” suffers from ecological
degradation, funding and programs for ecological improvement
became an important part of WRD. In Inner Mongolia, funds for
tree planting have increased, including rewards for people who
convert rain-fed cropland to the planting of trees (Feng 2000).
The “ecological migration” program emerged in this context. In
Ih Ju league, 10,000 people were on the move list in 2001. The
league plans to move 68,000 people by 2005. In Uxin Ju, 100
households in the most sandy Buridu gacha were on the
move list, and each household was to be subsidized by 20,000
Yuan ($2,400) to settle in Chahanmiao, a local town. Use of
their allocated pastureland will be banned for five years, by
which time, if the pastureland recovers, people can then move
back. Since life in the town has been an attractive alternative
to pastoral life, more households desire to join the program
than the government funds can assist. We have yet to see the
success of such temporary relocation. The idea of permanent
closure of degraded areas has also been contemplated by the
regional and local governments, and development of small towns
is seen as the primary way to absorb the relocated population
(Interviews 2001).
Other than strict conservation, programs
that restrain use have also been tested. One program
experimented with by Ih-Ju league is a move toward grazing bans
on all pastures during the entire warm season, so that
pastureland degradation can be alleviated. The pastoralists in
Uxin Ju reacted with serious doubts. During interviews in 2001,
my informants voiced concerns about not having enough labor to
care for livestock raised in stalls; they also questioned
whether it is suitable to keep sheep in stalls and whether that
practice would deteriorate the quality of sheep wool, a main
market product of the local economy. Moreover, they feared that
the grazing ban would undermine the household economy. The local
government officials realize the danger of economic compromise.
As one administrator in Ih-Ju League put it, the “(Grazing ban)
uses the local people’s economic interests in exchange for the
nation’s ecological benefit; the (central) government should
lend us financial support” (Interviews 2001). The support that
has come has been sorely insufficient, leaving the local
government scrambling to meet both economic and ecological
goals.
Conclusion
In the previous two chapters in this
volume, Sundberg and Gray have each explored problems of
decentralized resource use at the community level that
originated in political processes. This paper examines
household-based pastureland management in China from ecological
and cultural perspectives. Echoing Sundberg and Gray, I show
that decentralization in Inner Mongolia has not delivered the
desired outcome of sustainable use and economic empowerment for
all. After the pastureland was distributed to households and
fenced, more intense use has followed, leading to pastureland
degradation. Means’ (1993) warning of detrimental environmental
impacts of pastureland privatization has not been heeded. Even
more important, efforts to fix the mobile sand have created
their own set of unintended problems. While the sandy land has
been more aggressively reclaimed through the planting of trees,
shrubs, grass and even crops, sand continues to move across
fences, creating conflicts between neighbors. Moreover,
ecological processes operate at the landscape level, and
improvements in certain areas, which draw on and thus lower the
groundwater level, only serve to exacerbate degradation at other
locations that are more vulnerable (i.e. more sandy locations or
the lowland). Thus, uneven landscape change has occurred.
Although initial distribution of pastureland was based upon
equality among all individuals, post-distribution variability in
landscape change has led some to bear more than their fair share
of pastureland degradation, since household-based pastureland
use in the reform era has effectively eliminated the sharing of
ecological and economic risks in the community. Decentralization
in Uxin Ju has created winners and losers, not through struggle
to access as in the cases of Sundberg and Gray, but because of
the mismatch between dynamic ecological changes and the bounded
decentralized resource use at the household level.
Another important consequence of
pastureland privatization and sandy land reclamation concerns
changes in lifestyle. As pastures are fenced, and trees, shrubs,
and crops planted, the nomadic lifestyle becomes impossible.
Uxin Ju is going through rapid transformations, and most people
are eager to accept these changes. Still, reclamation with
fences leaves little room for traditional grazing practices,
thereby placing an additional burden on the pastoralists to
accept change as a new way of life. This is not to say that
these changes are entirely detrimental to the society. While
nomadic mobility is disappearing, the Mongols have gained other
kinds of mobility, including economic mobility and increased
opportunity to adopt an expanded array of economic and land-use
practices. However, the alternative mobility cannot replace the
important ecological and cultural value of nomadic mobility.
Gray (this volume) questions whether
community is the right scale for resource management; my study
casts doubts on households as an appropriate level of use due to
the inconsistency of household- and fence-based grassland use
with local ecological and cultural processes. Policy
implications of this study are threefold. First, to consider
ecological processes at the landscape level, household resource
use must be assisted with collective management, taking
ecological science seriously. Second, the community must build
socio-economic mechanisms to alleviate economic inequalities;
only then would sound collective management be possible. Lastly,
elements of traditional nomadism should be considered,
especially for the seriously degraded areas that call for
stricter conservation. This study shows that decentralization
has offered some hope for economic growth and grassland
improvement, but more challenges for long-term sustainable use.
References
Assetto, V. J., E. Hajba, and S. P. Mumme.
2003. Democratization, decentralization, and local environmental
policy capacity: Hungary and Mexico. The Social Science
Journal 40 (2): 249-68
Bakir, H.A. 2001. Sustainable wastewater
management for small communities in the Middle East and North
Africa. Journal of Environmental Management 61 (4):
319-28.
Banks, T. 2001. Property rights and
the environment in pastoral China: Evidence from the field.
Development and Change 32(4): 717-40.
Barfield, T. J. 1989. The perilous
frontier. Nomadic empires and China, 221 BC to AD 1757.
Cambridge, MA: Blackwell.
Behnke, R.H., I.
Scoones and C. Kerven. 1994. Range ecology at
disequilibrium: New models of natural variability and pastoral
adaptation in African savannas. Westview Press.
Bennett, R. J. ed. 1990.
Decentralization, local governments and markets. Oxford:
Clarendon Press.
Brandon, K., K. H.
Redford, and S. Sanderson. 1998. Parks in peril:
People, politics, and protected areas. Island Press.
Lavigne,
M. 1999. The economics of
transition: From socialist economy to market economy. New
York: St. Martin's Press.
Chen, Y. 2001. Meng gu zu wen hua de sheng
tai xue si kao (Ecological implication of Mongolian culture).
Nei Meng Gu She Hui Ke Xue (Social Science of Inner Mongolia),
No. 5: 34-37.
de Oliveria, J. A. P. 2002. Implementing
environmental policies in developing countries through
decentralization: The case of protected areas in Bahia, Brazil.
World Development 30 (10): 1713-36.
Feng, G. 2000. Tui geng huan lin zheng ce
fen xi yu jian yi (Policy analysis and recommendations for
returning cultivation to trees). Lin Ye Jing Ji (Forestry
Economics) No. 5: 6-13.
Huang Z. et al. 1986. Nei meng gu
yi ke zhao meng tu di sha mo hua ji qi fang zhi (Desertification
and its control in Ih Ju league, Inner Mongolia). Zhong Guo
Ke Xue Yuan Lan Zhou Shan Mo Yan Jiu Suo Ji Kan (Memoirs of
Institute of Desert, Academia Sinica) No. 3: 35-48.
Humphrey, C., and D. Sneath, eds. 1999.
End of nomadism? Society, state and the environment in Inner
Asia. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.
Jia, H, and Z. Lin. 1994. Changing
central-local relations in
China.
Boulder: Westview.
Jiang, H. 1999. The Ordos Plateau of
China: An Endangered Environment. Tokyo: United Nations
University Press.
Jiang, H. 2004. Cooperation, land use, and
the environment in Uxin Ju: A changing landscape of a
Mongolian-Chinese borderland in China. Annals of
Association of American Geographers 94 (1): 117-39.
Jiang, H. n.d. Decentralization,
ecological construction, and the environment in post-reform
China: Case study from Uxin banner, Inner Mongolia. World
Development.
Kung, J. K., and S. Liu. 1997.
Farmers’ preferences regarding ownership and land tenure in
post-Mao China: Unexpected evidence from eight counties. The
China Journal
No. 38: 33-63.
Lane, M. B. 2003. Decentralization or
privatization of environmental governance? Forest conflict and
bioregional assessment in Australia. Journal of Rural Studies
19 (3): 283-94.
Leach, M., R. Mearns, and I. Scoones.
1999. Environmental entitlements: Dynamics and institutions in
community-based natural resource management. World
Development 27 (2): 225-47.
Lin, G. (1999). State policy and
spatial restructuring in post-reform China, 1978-95.
International Journal of Urban Research, 23(4), 670-97.
Liu, M., and Y. Wang. 1998. Yi ke zhao
meng cao ku lun jian she he li yong diao cha bao gao
(Investigation report on the construction and use of pasture
enclosure in Ih Ju League). Nei Meng Gu Cao Ye (Inner
Mongolia Grass Industry), No. 2: 17-19.
Lutz, E., and J. Caldecott, eds. 1996.
Decentralization and biodiversity conservation. Washington
D.C.: The World Bank.
McMillan, J., and B. Naughton. 1996.
Reforming Asian socialism: The growth of market institutions.
Ann Arbor, MI: The University of Michigan Press.
Means, R. 1993. Territoriality and land
tenure among Mongolian pastoralists: variation, continuity, and
change. Nomadic Peoples 33: 73-103.
Nemarundwe, N. 2004.
Social charters and organisation for
access to woodlands: Institutional implications for devolving
responsibilities for resource management to the local level in
Chivi district, Zimbabwe.
Society and Natural Resources, 17(4): 279-91.
Naughton-Treves, L., V. C. Radeloff, J. L.
Mena, A. Treves, and N. Alvarez 2003. Wildlife Survival Beyond
Park Boundaries: The Impact of Slash-and-Burn Agriculture and
Hunting on Mammals in Tambopata, Peru. Conservation Biology
17 (4): 1106-17.
Ribot, J. C. 1999. Accountable
representation and power in participatory and decentralized
environmental management. Unasylva 50, No.199: 18-22.
Shroeder, R.A. 1999. Geographies of
environmental intervention in Africa. Progress in Human
Geography 23(3): 359-78.
Sun, J. 1990. Er er duo si gao yuan sheng
tai huan jing zheng zh de zhan lue yan jin (Strategic analysis
of eco-environmental control of the Ordos Plateau). Gan Han
Qu Zi Yuan Yu Huan Jing (Journal of Arid Land Resources and
Environment) 4(4): 45-50.
Sundberg, J. 1999. Conservation
encounters: NGOs, local people, and changing cultural
landscapes. Dissertation, Geography Department, University
of Texas, Austin.
Thwaites, R, T. de Lacy, Y. H. Li, and X.
H. Liu. 1998. Property rights, social change, and grassland
degradation in Xilingol Biosphere Reserve, Inner Mongolia,
China. Society and Natural Resources 11 (4): 319-38.
Turner, M. 1999. Central-local
relations: Themes and issues. In Central-local relations in
Asia-Pacific: Convergence or
divergence, ed. M.
Turner, 1-28, Hampshire, UK: Macmillan Press.
Turner, M. 2002. Moral dimensions of
“resource struggles” and their treatment in political ecology.
Paper presented at the Annual meeting of AAG, March 22, Los
Angeles, CA.
Unger, J. 2002. The transformation
of rural China. New York: M. E. Sharpe.
Weber, E. P. 2000. A new vanguard for
the environment: grass-roots ecosystem management as a new
environmental movement. Society and Natural Resources 13
(3): 237-59.
Williams, D. M. 2001. Beyond the Great
Wall: Environment, identidy, and development on the Chinese
grasslands of Inner Mongolia. Stanford, CA: Stanford
University Press.
Williams, M. D., and M. P. Wells.
1996. Russia. In Decentralization and biodiversity
conservation, eds. E. Lutz and J. Caldecott, 109-122.
Washington D.C.: The World Bank.
World Bank. 1997. World development
report: The state in a changing world. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Wu, J., and O. Loucks 1995. From balance
of nature to hierarchical patch dynamics: A paradigm shift in
ecology. Quarterly Review of Biology 70: 439-66.
Wushen Qi (Uxin banner). 2001. (Wushen
qi jinmu xiumu lunmu zaixing banfa (Temporary regulations in
rotational grazing and closing of pastureland from grazing).
Unpublished government document.
Zhang, T. 2000. Land market forces and
government’s role in sprawl: The case of China. Cities 17
(2): 123-35.
Zhang, X. 2001. Personal communication.
Figure 1. Map of Study Area
|