|
Monday, April 11, from 2:00 –
3:30 PM
Rayburn House Office
Building, Room 2255
Statement of
Christopher P. Atwood
I
would first like to express my appreciation for the opportunity
to appear today before the Congressional Executive Commission on
China and present my perspective on the question of “China’s
Regional Autonomy Law: Does it Protect Minority Rights?”
Rather than discuss the broad range of minority rights issues in
play in Inner Mongolia today, I would like to focus on the issue
of “ecological migration” which illustrates in a striking matter
how the guarantees of autonomy in the regional autonomy law fail
to provide protection against massive state-directed dislocation
of the Mongol nationality in China.1
The earliest versions of “ecological migration” were pioneered
in the early 1990s in Alashan district in far-western Inner
Mongolia under the moniker “three-ways labor restructuring.”
Responding to ongoing severe desertification and pasture
degradation in Inner Mongolia’s driest district, the Alashan
authorities started with the basic premise that excess
population and livestock are at the root of pasture degradation.
Their “three-ways restructuring” plan envisioned one-third of
the current pastoral population continuing as herders, one-third
switching to arable cultivation, and one-third entering township
or urban enterprises.2
In 2001, this basic idea was adopted by the Inner Mongolian
government and renamed “ecological migration.” The vastly
expanded plan involved moving up to 650,000 persons out of areas
where grasslands are being subject to serious degradation into
towns and other areas.3
Considerable sums are being assigned to build housing and other
infrastructure for the new migrants, although whether these sums
are adequate is controversial.4
In most areas it appears the relocations are not total with a
small number of herders regarded as rationally managing
rangeland being allowed to stay.5
Those relocated may return after five years if they too can
demonstrate an ability to manage the grassland “scientifically.”
Thus “ecological migration” is accelerating the trend to
polarization in which a small number of relatively well-off
herders (whether ethnically Mongol or Han Chinese) who have
assimilated contemporary Chinese ideas of proper livestock
management will continue herding, while the poorer, less
sophisticated herders will be forced off the land. This social
polarization corresponds to a polarization in the landscape
itself, in which slowing expanding oases of intensively managed
fodder and crop fields are set within rapidly growing desert
areas, both squeezing out the remaining areas of usable natural
grass pasture.
Any evaluation of “ecological migration” must deal with the
undeniable ecological crisis in Inner Mongolia and the legacy of
decades of over-reclamation and over-grazing. Massive dust
storms in Beijing have alerted China’s central government to the
seriousness of the situation. There exists a consensus among
outside observers that while overstocking of livestock,
particular sheep and goats valued for their wool and cashmere,
today is currently driving much pasture degradation,
historically it is over-reclamation of marginal lands for
farming that has damaged Inner Mongolian pastures the most.6
Although Inner Mongolian policy in 1984 officially prohibited
further reclamation of pasture, the 2003 land-use law in Inner
Mongolia appears to again encourage “wild-cat” land reclamation.7
Economically, the bankruptcy of smaller-scale, less capitalized
producers and their replacement by larger-scale commercialized
producers is a universal, if often painful, aspect of economic
development, although rarely so explicitly decreed by the
government as in this case.
In terms of human rights “ecological migration” raises serious
problems. On an individual level we can ask, are the transfers
truly voluntary? Are the residents being adequately compensated
and given the ability to make a living in their new homes?
Reports are contradictory. One geographer working in Ordos
reports that the possibility of a prosperous town life is
enticing for many poor herders, yet the fact that in this same
community the possibility of returning after five years is also
being touted as a concession/palliation indicates migrants may
have reasonable doubts of whether they will really succeed as
towns people.8
Other observers report cases of forcible eviction by the police
of communities unwilling to move.9
Undoubtedly implementation of such a vast program differs widely
in the localities. Yet it would be naive to put too much stock
in the possibility of the implementation of such movement being
fully voluntary. “Ecological migration” is now government
policy, adopted without significant public input and those
slated for migration are undoubtedly aware that resistance is
futile.10
As with any issue of (broadly speaking) eminent domain, i.e. use
of government power to abridge citizens’ existing property
rights, the question is, does this abridgement
disproportionately affect one community more than another and
was the decision taken with input from all the affected
communities?
Since pasture degradation is linked to the dynamics of herding
and farming, an issue with long ethnic repercussions in Inner
Mongolia, the “ecological migration” issue must also be seen in
the light of minority rights. Nomadic pastoralism was the
traditional way of life for most Mongols up to the twentieth
century and the herding life has been the font of Mongol values,
art, literature, and national feeling. Although the pastoral
Mongols in Inner Mongolia had largely shifted to shifted to
sedentary ranching by the 1980s, herding remains important for
the Mongols, both practically and symbolically.
Yet I would like to dispose of a red herring immediately.
“Ecological migration” is often cast as a conflict of purely
traditional Mongols, seen as stubbornly attached to rural life
and pastoral nomadism for cultural reasons, and Han Chinese
practicing innovative, high-productivity land use. In reality,
however, the Mongols of Inner Mongolia are highly educated with
strong aspirations to success in the modern sector. In fact
their literacy rate is slightly higher than the Han Chinese, and
they are over-represented in the ranks of cadres.11
Pastoralists in Inner Mongolian are more commercialized and have
a higher income than farmers.12
For better or for worse, Mongol herders have been quite as
willing to adopt the new intensive managerial strategy of
herding.13
At the same time, the contention that this managerial ranching
will be less harmful to the steppe than nomadic pastoralism is
quite dubious scientifically; in fact increasing, not
decreasing, mobility may be the key to saving the grasslands.14
What is beyond doubt is that the almost twenty years of
state-directed and scientifically managed programs to alleviate
grasslands degradation have not worked and indeed may well have
accelerated desertification.15
The issue is thus not modernization vs. tradition, but ensuring
that the Mongols have meaningful voice in the nature of the
modernization of their own communities.
“Ecological migration” thus remains an ethnic issue. Although
Han Chinese herders and farmers in affected areas are also being
deported, the Mongols remain the predominant population group in
the arid regions of Inner Mongolia slated for population
removal, and hence are being disproportionately influenced by
ecological migration.16
These arid grasslands constitute the heartlands of ethnic Mongol
life, where they are the local majority and dominate their
community as the long resident native population. Until the
2001, Mongolian language, social standards, and culture still
formed the norm in these remote areas to which the immigrant Han
Chinese partially conformed.17
Ecological migration is breaking up many, if not most, of these
last redoubts of Mongol community life in Inner Mongolia. In
their new environments, the resettled migrants will often lack
proper skills and aptitudes for their new occupations. Indeed by
moving the most traditional and least capitalized and
managerials-style herders, the authorities are choosing also the
ones least likely to adapt to urban life. When settled on the
outskirts of predominantly Han cities and towns, the Mongols
often lack Mongol-language schools and become marginal residents
in a culturally and socially alien environment. Already there
are alarming signs of dramatic drops in income among the
resettled migrants as well as sharp drops in school attendance
as relocated Mongol students find themselves with either no
local schools, or only Chinese-language ones.18
Ecological migration thus runs directly contrary to any minority
right to preserve its own communal life. Before 1947, pasture in
un-reclaimed Mongol steppe was held collectively by the “banner”
(or county-level unit). Decades of political and social conflict
along the Mongol-Han frontier before 1947 had revolved around
the Mongols’ tenacious and resourceful attempts to protect these
collective land rights from encroachment by Han Chinese
land-developers and their allies in the provincial governments.
From the very inception of Chinese Communist land reform,
however, land was transferred to the Chinese state, with rural
producers being granted only longer or shorter leases. The
deprivation of land-rights has hardly affected only Mongols or
minorities; collectivization in 1956 and the current rampant
abuse of government powers of eminent domain to facilitate urban
sprawl are two other particularly egregious examples of this
cavalier disregard of land rights.19
Articles 27 and 28 of the Law on Regional National Autonomy
discuss land use and give the autonomous regions the right to
determine ownership of pastures and forests. The same articles,
however, absolutely prohibit any “damage” to the grasslands by
individuals or collectives, and call on the autonomous
authorities to give “priority to the rational exploitation and
utilization of the natural resources that the local authorities
are entitled to develop.” Technocracy thus explicitly trumps any
and all land rights. The ongoing destruction of Mongol local
community life involved in ecological migration is thus fully in
accord with and indeed may actually be mandated by China’s
regional national autonomy law, as long as one accepts the
disputed premise that nomadism and overstocking are behind
desertification.
Still, if Inner Mongolia’s regional national autonomous organs
actually spoke for the Mongol nationality, then the articles 27
and 28 would still give the Mongols input into these
technocratic land use decisions. This is, however, not the case.
Along with the rejection of banner communal land-ownership in
1947, the newly-created Inner Mongolian Autonomous Region also
rejected the then common practice of over-lapping Han and Mongol
local jurisdictions (Han counties or xian and Mongol banners) in
favor of unitary local government. Inner Mongolia was eventually
expanded to include most of China’s far-flung Mongol
communities, but only at the price of thereby acquiring an
overwhelming Han majority. At the prefectural and county levels,
administrative changes ostensibly intended to give each unit a
balance of agricultural and pastoral economies frequently yoked
sparsely settled majority-Mongol districts with vastly more
populous Han-majority districts. As a result, only in the arid
zone townships (sumu) and in some purely steppe banners do
Mongols actually predominate in government.20
At the prefectural and all-regional levels, Mongol cadres have
the worst of both worlds: over-represented enough through
“affirmative action” to generate resentment, but not numerous
enough to actually control decision-making in Mongol interests.
21 This does not
even take into account the power of the central government in
Beijing. Thus the regional national autonomous organs simply
cannot act as protectors of specifically Mongol ethnic
interests.
Now, no one can deny that it would be fundamentally unfair for
decision-making in a region only 16% Mongol, as Inner Mongolia
as a whole is, to be monopolized by Mongols. Yet apart from such
a monopoly, it is hard to see how the Mongols as a group can be
said to have had any meaningful voice in the momentous decision
taken in 2001 to remove whole communities from their ancient
ancestral homes. Under Chinese law, regional national autonomy
is for better or for worse the only organ through which the
minority nationalities exercise their collective right to
autonomy, yet in a region with borders drawn wherever possible
to combine Han and Mongol communities, such an autonomy cannot
help but be fictitious. As a result, “ecological migration,”
despite its origin within the Inner Mongolian bureaucracy, is
one more example of the inability of Chinese regional national
autonomy, as currently structured, to allow the legitimate
concerns of minorities to even be voiced openly, let alone
prevail in the public arena.
Notes:
-
Information on ecological migration is very
difficult to obtain, a fact which by itself casts doubt on
whether the policy’s rationale and implications have been
sufficiently debated. In preparing this paper I have been
greatly assisted by the panelists at the panel “Ecological
Migration: Environment, Ethnicity, and Human Rights in
Inner
Mongolia,” which I chaired at the Association for Asian
Studies (AAS) Annual Meeting in Chicago on
April 3, 2005. I would like to thank the panelists Judith Shapiro
(American University), Jeannine Brown (graduate student,
University of East London), Hong Jiang (University of
Wisconsin at Madison), S. Sodbilig (Inner Mongolia
University), and Enhebatu Togochag (Southern Mongolian Human
Rights Information Center) for their very informative and
insightful papers and comments.
-
A. Hurelbaatar, “A Survey of the Mongols in
Present-Day
China:
Perspectives on Demography and Culture Change,” in
Mongolia in
the Twentieth Century: Landlocked Cosmopolitan, ed. Stephen Kotkin and Bruce A. Elleman (Armonk: M.E.
Sharpe, 1999), p. 201.
-
A key question about which data remains scarce is
the actual destinations of “ecological migrants.” In Üüshin
Juu sumu
(Mongol township), Hong Jiang found that ecological migrants
were being directed not to the mostly Mongol township center,
but to the new town (zhen) of Chaghan Süme (Chinese Chahanmiao) with a
population of over 10,000 that are “mostly migrants from
outside the area” recruited to exploit a natural gas field
(Hong Jiang, “Fences, Ecologies, and Changes in Pastoral Life:
Sandy Land Reclamation in Uxin Ju, Inner Mongolia, China”
[unpublished paper], and “Cooperation, Land Use, and the
Environment in Uxin Ju: The Changing Landscape of a
Mongol-Chinese Borderland in China,”
Annals of the Association of
American Geographers,” 94.1 [2004], p. 129). In
Alashan it appears that half of the herders or 20-25,000 were
originally to be resettled on a 70,000 hectare oasis
communities as farmers, although the construction of this
oasis seems to be currently mired in corruption, incompetence,
and flawed science (Jeannine W. Brown,
State Sponsored Resettlement
in Inner Mongolia: A Case Study in Environmental Forced
Migration [M.A. Thesis, University of East London,
2004], pp. 35-36; “Irresponsible cultivation causes
desertification, environmental destruction threatens Beijing,”
August 21, 2004,
at http://www.smhric.org/news_45.htm, accessed
April 13, 2005). Many of the migrants are slated to become sedentary
dairy farmers working with foreign-breed milk cows; see Brown,
op. cit., pp.
43-44.
-
In
Ordos, migrants receive 20,000
yuan ($2,400)
being given to each migrant (Jiang, “Fences, Ecologies, and
Changes in Pastoral Life”). In Chakhar, Mongol herders being
moved due to the production of a power plant received 10,000
yuan ($1,100)
if they agreed to renounce all return to their previous
pastures; those who wish to retain their right to return would
receive only a mud-brick house worth 5,000
yuan ($550) and
would have to purchase an Australian milk cow; see “Power
Plant Project Forces Local Mongols to Abandon Ancestral
Lands,”
September 4, 2003,
at http://www.smhric.org/news_30.htm (accessed
April 6, 2005).
-
In Ereen Khot (Erlian) the city boundaries were
recently expanded to include pastures with 354 herding
households. Of these only 50-80 have been chosen to be allowed
to stay on the land to promote “animal husbandry for tourism.”
See “Ereen Hot municipality lends every effort to implement
ecological migration project,”
August 8, 2004,
at http://www.smhric.org/news_43.htm (accessed
April 13, 2005). 100 households are being moved from Büridü
gachaa (a
sub-township unit) in Üüshin Juu township (Jiang, “Fences,
Ecologies, and Changes in Pastoral Life”); the only figure on
the total population of that
gachaa available
to me, that of 210 households in 1984 (Nei
Menggu Zizhiqu diming zhi: Yike Zhao meng fence [Höhhot:
Inner Mongolian Autonomous Region Local Names Commission,
1986], p. 326), would indicate that roughly a third of the
households are being moved.
-
Dennis Sheehy, “Grazing Management Strategies as
a Factor Influencing Ecological Stability of Mongolian
Grasslands,” Nomadic
Peoples 33 (1993), pp. 17-30, esp. pp. 26-27.
-
“Inner Mongolian authorities carry out new
policies: Land use first, formalities later on”
June 24, 2003 at http://www.smhric.org/news_27.htm (accessed
April 6, 2005).
-
See Hong Jiang, “Fences, Ecologies, and Changes
in Pastoral Life.”
-
GardiBorjigin,“InnerMongolianEnvironmentThreatened,NomadsForcedtoMove,”athttp://www.expertclick.com/NewsReleaseWire/default.cfm?Action=ReleaseDetail&ID=8211
(accessed
April 6,
2005).
-
In April, 2002, a speech by CCP Politburo member
Jiang Chunyun on tour in eastern
Inner Mongolia
monitored by the BBC made it clear that effectively
implementing ecological migration will be the test for any
cadre who hopes for promotion. “Any cadres in desertified
areas who fail to attach importance to the environment should
not be cadres; those who fail to build a sound environment are
not good cadres. . . In areas where desertification is serious
and where the conditions for human survival are more or less
lost, ecological migration should be conducted.” Jiang
Chunyun’s remarks on this tour are one of
theclearestexpression’softhecentralgovernment’sviewsonenvironmentalpolicyinInnerMongolia.Seehttp://coranet.radicalparty.org/pressreview/print_right.php?func=detail&par=3268
(accessed April 13, 2005).
-
Song Naigong,
Zhongguo renkou (Nei Menggu
fence) (Beijing: China Finance and Economics
Press, 1987), pp. 363, 359-361
-
Nei Menggu da
cidian
(Höhhot: Inner Mongolia People’s Press, 1991), pp. 275, 296.
-
Hong Jiang, “Cooperation, Land Use, and the
Environment in Uxin Ju,” pp. 117-139.
-
This was the conclusion reached by the large
Macarthur Project; see Caroline Humphrey and David Sneath,
The End of Nomadism? Soceity,
State and the Environment in
Inner Mongolia
(Durham: Duke University Press), esp. pp. 292-93.
-
Dennis Sheehy,
op. cit.; Dee
Mack Williams, Beyond
Great Walls: Environment, Identity, and Development on the
Chinese Grasslands of
Inner
Mongolia
(Stanford: Stanford University Press, 2002), esp. pp. 117-137;
Hong Jiang, op. cit., esp. fig. 9.
-
A BBC
broadcast includes interviews with Han farmers from Taipusi
Banner and Mongolian herders from around Shiliin Gol both
being affected by “ecological migration”; see http://www.bbc.co.uk/worldservice/programmes/ram/parched_lands/parched_lands3.ram
(accessed April 6, 2005). While no ethnic breakdown has been
released, the ethnic demography of Inner Mongolia and the
overwhelming testimony of observers agree that mostly Mongols
are being affected.
-
Burton
Pasternak and Janet W. Salaff,
Cowboys and Cultivators: The
Chinese of
Inner Mongolia
(Boulder: Westview, 1993), pp. 143-253.
-
A study of
111 households relocated in Sönid Right Banner showed their
average incomes dropping from 2,872
yuan before
relocation in 2000 to 503
yuan after relocation in 2002. At the same time
their debt load rose from 0
yuan to
7,000-8,000 yuan.
Enrollment in Inner Mongolia’s elementary schools dropped
19.4% from 2002 to 2003. See Enhebatu Togochog, “Ecological
Immigration and Human Rights,” paper presented at the Annual
Meeting of the AAS,
April 3, 2005.
-
Abuses of
eminent domain are also found in Inner Mongolia; see for example “Power Plant Project Forces Local Mongols to
Abandon Ancestral Lands,”
September 4,
2003, at http://www.smhric.org/news_30.htm (accessed
April 6, 2005).
-
The sumu
is a Mongol township; typically Mongols monopolize local
government and police in the
sumu even where
Han migrants make up a large percentage or even a majority of
the residents. See for example Pasternak and Salaff,
Cowboys and Cultivators,
esp. pp. 170-172. The special administrative terms used in
Inner Mongolia’s Mongol regions are as follows:
Regular Chinese terms |
Inner Mongolia’s Mongol areas |
province |
Autonomous Region |
prefecture or municipality |
league (aimag in
Mongolian, meng
in Chinese) |
county (xian) |
banner (khoshuu
in
Mongolia,
qi in
Chinese) |
township (xiang) |
sumu |
-
William B.
Jankowiak, in his Sex,
Death, and Hierarchy in a Chinese City: An Anthropological
Account (New York: Columbia University Press,
1993), pp. 33-37, 303, stresses the resentment which
preferential policies for Mongols raise among Han in Inner
Mongolia’s capital, Höhhot; Uradyn E. Bulag describes the
ethnic and regional factionalism in Inner Mongolian government
in his “Dialectics of Colonization and Ethnicity Building,” in
Governing China’s
Multiethnic Frontiers, ed. Morris Rossabi
(Seattle: University of Washington Press, 2004), pp. 84-116.
|